Law in the Internet Society

View   r3  >  r2  >  r1
LinusKatzenbachFirstEssay 3 - 07 Jan 2025 - Main.LinusKatzenbach
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="FirstEssay"
Changed:
<
<

Exclusive Ownership of Software

>
>

Exclusive Ownership of Software: Balancing Innovation, Access, and Legal Framework

 
Changed:
<
<
-- By LinusKatzenbach - 25 Oct 2024
>
>
-- By LinusKatzenbach - Initial Draft 25 Oct 2024 - Second Draft 7 Jan 2025
 

Introduction

Changed:
<
<
Software is the defining feature of technological progress and skyrocketing productivity in today’s Internet Society. Therefore, the question is not if software should be subject to legal regulation but rather how these rules and standards are best designed. Although this being a normative question as legal regulation is rarely a question of right or wrong but of morals and ideology, due to the technological nature of software, these circumstances have to be considered as well.
>
>
Software dominates modern life, playing a vital role in commerce, communication, and education. Unsurprisingly, debates about the ownership of software and how such is enforced have become more and more relevant. As traditional property law, and even its extensions into patents and copyrights, does not easily provide guidance for these questions in the intangible world of software, diverging philosophies about exclusive versus free and open models exist, revealing competing priorities around innovation, access, and societal benefit.
 
Changed:
<
<
When thinking about “Software Law”, I would expect the reader to first have a variety of specific pieces of regulation come to mind (to give a rather recent example, the approaches by the European Union to hold platform provider accountable for misconduct by their users through the Digital Services Act) that only became necessary because of certain issues (or characteristics as a more neutral description) that software poses to our modern society requiring legal solutions that haven’t been developed before.
>
>

Historical Context

 
Changed:
<
<
But the advent of software also challenges as to re-think well delevoped and thought-out legal concepts that have stood for centuries and might not be able to properly grasp the individualities of software as subject of legal regulation. Hence, it proves difficult to assess wherever these concepts and rules need to be modified for they would be impractical when used in the realm of software.
>
>
In the early decades of computing source code was often shared freely among researchers and hobbyists. This open exchange shifted in the 1970s and 80s as commercial interests realized code could be licensed and monetized, a development that is best exemplified by Bill Gates' famous 1976 "Open letter to Hobbyists" demanding payment for copied software. Gradually, new legislation extended copyright and patent protection to software, culminating in the Digital Millennium Copyright Act (DMCA). At the same time, however, the GNU project emerged in the 1980s, promoting a conception of software freedom that grants users the right to study, modify, and share source code, at their choice. At its center is the GNU General Public License (GPL), which challenges whether software, being a product infinitely reproducible at negligible cost, should be governed by restrictive ownership rules. This same realization of possibly endless duplication is also used as an argument against proprietary models by legal scholar Eben Moglen in "Anarchism Triumphant: Free Software and the Death of Copyright" as strong ownership rules may not fully serve either innovation or society's collective interests. In this direction it is also argued that strong property regulation restricts collaboration, slows the flow of ideas, and overlook social benefits that come with open, cooperative production.
 
Changed:
<
<
This essay aims to address this question having at hand what may be the most fundamental of these old concepts (at least in the field of private law, here understood as the law governing the legal relationship between natural or legal persons as private entities): property. It is not a characteristic of American Law but inherent to all (at least Western, to not need to argue about the capitalistic-centered works view this writer may or may not have) legal systems, to possess rules attributing rights to a person being in possession of an object allowing him to do it or do not do with that object what he pleases, including, only consequentially, excluding others from their access to this very object, may it be altogether or depending on their willingness of adhering to certain demands, such as the payment of money.
>
>

The Case For Exclusive Ownership

 
Changed:
<
<
While this exclusion proves itself practical when applied to material objects, the introduction of the legal concepts of patents and copyrights became necessary to continue using this property-focused structure in regards to immaterial, or “intellectual” property like logos and trademarks. While these concepts are practically closer to being able to be applied to software, these structural similarities don’t provide justification to do exactly that.
>
>
Proponents of exclusive ownership argue that developing and maintaining high-quality software demands costly investments. Without the prospect of return of investment through licenses or subscription fees, private entities might not have an incentive to pursue costly research and development. In safety-critical or regulated industries, proprietary control can also facilitate accountability: a singular owner is responsible for implementing security measures, providing updates, and adhering to legal standards.
 
Changed:
<
<
Admittedly, software shares with with traditional patents and copyrights the characteristic that it is built upon public accessible information. Whereas, example given, a logo is made up of lines, colors and geometric shapes, software consists of code in some programming language that is no one’s property but available for anyone to use. There can also be brought forward the argument that both are the product of some creative or thought-and-time-consuming process, which may justify protection by certain rights of property. On the other hand, software is never the end product. Unlike a logo or a song that is made to be looked at or to be listened to, in any way consumed, software is merely, or maybe more so, a tool for others, To bolster others productivity, to allow for their own creative process, or just to ease everyday life by enabling communication, navigation, or food delivery.
>
>
Some scholars also posit that well-defined property rights, including copyrights and patents, stipulate innovation by granting time-limited monopolies that reward risk-taking. By channeling revenue back into development, proprietary software firms can fund high-level technical support, bug fixes, and future product improvement.
 
Changed:
<
<
These arguments point out that the question at hand is not an easy one. Software is a phenomenon of its own and does not fit into previously existing categories. Therefore, it is time to examine the points that can be made in favor and against property-like protection of software.
>
>

The Case Against Exclusive Ownership

 
Changed:
<
<

Arguments against such a protection

>
>
On the other hand, it is argued that closed-sourced models can hinder collaboration, and foster monopolies or oligopolies. In contrast, open-source communities depend on peer review and decentralized contributions, which can lead to more robust and secure products. Access is another concern, with proprietary systems often keeping code inaccessible, limiting the user community's ability to identify vulnerabilities or propose enhancements. Licensing fees make software unaffordable for many individuals, schools, and nonprofits, potentially widening the digital divide. Also, exclusive ownership can limit the flexibility needed to tailor software to specialized or local needs, thus constraining broader innovation.
 
Changed:
<
<
First, software thrives on collective knowledge and shared expertise. No program is perfect or ever-finished, and open-source software, which allows multiple contributors to collaborate and improve upon existing projects, has demonstrated the power of shared effort. The treatment of software as property can create barriers to such a collaboration and sharing amongst developers and, therefore, may stand in the way of technological progress and the creation of robust and adaptable software solutions.
>
>

Hybrid and Nuanced Approaches

 
Changed:
<
<
Second, given the vital role of software in almost every realm of modern life, limited access to technology can severely impact one’s personal and professional development. If essential software is too expensive and therefore inaccessible to certain individuals or communities, the following lack of access to educational opportunities, job prospects, and overall participation in the digital economy, can increase existing inequalities. Instead, open access to software could level the playing field, allowing each and every individual to benefit from technological progress.

Arguments in favor of such a protection

It was already laid out that software is never perfect, and that with ongoing use, ongoing patchwork is necessary in order to maintain a high quality of user experience. Exclusive ownership attributes the program’s responsibility to the owner. Free software, on the other hand, might be copied at any stage of development, or modified in any way, without the user being aware posing a threat to the security of his private information or the integrity of his hardware.

Furthermore, developing software is a costly process that might only be worth pursuing if there is an incentive to do so. While with open access there is no money to be earned, the model of exclusive ownership provides clear rewards that make the investment of time, effort, and resources worth it. Exclusive ownership, therefore, is fundamental for encouraging innovation within the software industry.

>
>
Governments shape the balance between exclusive and open models. While the DMCA in the U.S. strengthens copyrights for digital works, including software, in the EU, the Digital Services Act (DSA) introduces rules seeking to ensure transparency in digital markets, marking an ongoing effort to reconcile corporate interests with consumer protection and welfare. Continuing these ideas of compromise, one path forward could be dual-licensing models that combine open accessibility for fundamental software components with proprietary rights for specialized or premium features. This hybrid approach offers revenue streams for continued financing for further development while still allowing for community-driven improvements. From a policy perspective, from some categories of software might be expected a higher degree of openness than from others. It would make sense, for example, to expect looser property frameworks regarding educational tools which should be accessible for everyone while stricter regulation seems to be in order for safety-critical systems where there needs to be an accountable owner. Such models, therefore, seek to acknowledge the economic realities of software production while preserving the collaborative advantage and accessibility of open approaches.
 

Conclusion

Changed:
<
<
In summary, exclusive ownership of software can be credited with incentivizing innovation and ensure quality maintenance, while also limiting productive collaboration, and equal and broad access. Balancing these factors is essential for fostering a thriving technological landscape.
>
>
Questions about software ownership expose deeper conflictive interests between rewarding creators and fostering collective advancement and innovation. Exclusive rights can fund development and clarify responsibility but may inhibit collaboration and exclude those without the means to pay. To reconcile both of these points a modern approach must account for both the economic costs of development and the societal value of open sharing. Such a middle ground could be a hybrid solution, where some aspects of software remain proprietary while others are freely accessible. This requires a nuanced discussion of how technology law, economics and social equity intersect in the realm of software.
 

Added:
>
>
THAT IS THE FEEDBACK FOR THE FIRST VERSION. NOW, THE SECOND VERSION HAS BEEN UPLOADED
  There's nothing here. The cloud of words contains mere empty rhetoric. There are no specifics about technology, politics or law. No sources of any kin d are referred to; no other person's ideas are described, interrogated, or responded to. "Arguments" without substance "for" and "against" a proposition without texture have been presented in an impersonally thoughtless monotone. Whether this is a bot mindlessly imitating a human or a human thoughtlessly imitating a bot doesn't matter: no learning or thinking is going on.

The subject is one about which I have done a great deal of work that we can see reflected everywhere around us in human society. I assigned writing by me and other people about the history, theory and practice of free software, spent hours of class time discussing it, have endeavored to present the most basic and the most advanced concepts in an accessible fashion, and not one syllable of the draft reflects any of this teaching. In traditional terms, this is failure.


LinusKatzenbachFirstEssay 2 - 16 Nov 2024 - Main.EbenMoglen
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="FirstEssay"
Line: 37 to 37
 

Conclusion

In summary, exclusive ownership of software can be credited with incentivizing innovation and ensure quality maintenance, while also limiting productive collaboration, and equal and broad access. Balancing these factors is essential for fostering a thriving technological landscape.

Added:
>
>

There's nothing here. The cloud of words contains mere empty rhetoric. There are no specifics about technology, politics or law. No sources of any kin d are referred to; no other person's ideas are described, interrogated, or responded to. "Arguments" without substance "for" and "against" a proposition without texture have been presented in an impersonally thoughtless monotone. Whether this is a bot mindlessly imitating a human or a human thoughtlessly imitating a bot doesn't matter: no learning or thinking is going on.

The subject is one about which I have done a great deal of work that we can see reflected everywhere around us in human society. I assigned writing by me and other people about the history, theory and practice of free software, spent hours of class time discussing it, have endeavored to present the most basic and the most advanced concepts in an accessible fashion, and not one syllable of the draft reflects any of this teaching. In traditional terms, this is failure.

The route to improvement, then, is to do the reading assigned, to write about the ideas encountered in it, and to take those ideas in some new direction of your choosing in relation to one or two of technology, politics, law.

 \ No newline at end of file

LinusKatzenbachFirstEssay 1 - 25 Oct 2024 - Main.LinusKatzenbach
Line: 1 to 1
Added:
>
>
META TOPICPARENT name="FirstEssay"

Exclusive Ownership of Software

-- By LinusKatzenbach - 25 Oct 2024

Introduction

Software is the defining feature of technological progress and skyrocketing productivity in today’s Internet Society. Therefore, the question is not if software should be subject to legal regulation but rather how these rules and standards are best designed. Although this being a normative question as legal regulation is rarely a question of right or wrong but of morals and ideology, due to the technological nature of software, these circumstances have to be considered as well.

When thinking about “Software Law”, I would expect the reader to first have a variety of specific pieces of regulation come to mind (to give a rather recent example, the approaches by the European Union to hold platform provider accountable for misconduct by their users through the Digital Services Act) that only became necessary because of certain issues (or characteristics as a more neutral description) that software poses to our modern society requiring legal solutions that haven’t been developed before.

But the advent of software also challenges as to re-think well delevoped and thought-out legal concepts that have stood for centuries and might not be able to properly grasp the individualities of software as subject of legal regulation. Hence, it proves difficult to assess wherever these concepts and rules need to be modified for they would be impractical when used in the realm of software.

This essay aims to address this question having at hand what may be the most fundamental of these old concepts (at least in the field of private law, here understood as the law governing the legal relationship between natural or legal persons as private entities): property. It is not a characteristic of American Law but inherent to all (at least Western, to not need to argue about the capitalistic-centered works view this writer may or may not have) legal systems, to possess rules attributing rights to a person being in possession of an object allowing him to do it or do not do with that object what he pleases, including, only consequentially, excluding others from their access to this very object, may it be altogether or depending on their willingness of adhering to certain demands, such as the payment of money.

While this exclusion proves itself practical when applied to material objects, the introduction of the legal concepts of patents and copyrights became necessary to continue using this property-focused structure in regards to immaterial, or “intellectual” property like logos and trademarks. While these concepts are practically closer to being able to be applied to software, these structural similarities don’t provide justification to do exactly that.

Admittedly, software shares with with traditional patents and copyrights the characteristic that it is built upon public accessible information. Whereas, example given, a logo is made up of lines, colors and geometric shapes, software consists of code in some programming language that is no one’s property but available for anyone to use. There can also be brought forward the argument that both are the product of some creative or thought-and-time-consuming process, which may justify protection by certain rights of property. On the other hand, software is never the end product. Unlike a logo or a song that is made to be looked at or to be listened to, in any way consumed, software is merely, or maybe more so, a tool for others, To bolster others productivity, to allow for their own creative process, or just to ease everyday life by enabling communication, navigation, or food delivery.

These arguments point out that the question at hand is not an easy one. Software is a phenomenon of its own and does not fit into previously existing categories. Therefore, it is time to examine the points that can be made in favor and against property-like protection of software.

Arguments against such a protection

First, software thrives on collective knowledge and shared expertise. No program is perfect or ever-finished, and open-source software, which allows multiple contributors to collaborate and improve upon existing projects, has demonstrated the power of shared effort. The treatment of software as property can create barriers to such a collaboration and sharing amongst developers and, therefore, may stand in the way of technological progress and the creation of robust and adaptable software solutions.

Second, given the vital role of software in almost every realm of modern life, limited access to technology can severely impact one’s personal and professional development. If essential software is too expensive and therefore inaccessible to certain individuals or communities, the following lack of access to educational opportunities, job prospects, and overall participation in the digital economy, can increase existing inequalities. Instead, open access to software could level the playing field, allowing each and every individual to benefit from technological progress.

Arguments in favor of such a protection

It was already laid out that software is never perfect, and that with ongoing use, ongoing patchwork is necessary in order to maintain a high quality of user experience. Exclusive ownership attributes the program’s responsibility to the owner. Free software, on the other hand, might be copied at any stage of development, or modified in any way, without the user being aware posing a threat to the security of his private information or the integrity of his hardware.

Furthermore, developing software is a costly process that might only be worth pursuing if there is an incentive to do so. While with open access there is no money to be earned, the model of exclusive ownership provides clear rewards that make the investment of time, effort, and resources worth it. Exclusive ownership, therefore, is fundamental for encouraging innovation within the software industry.

Conclusion

In summary, exclusive ownership of software can be credited with incentivizing innovation and ensure quality maintenance, while also limiting productive collaboration, and equal and broad access. Balancing these factors is essential for fostering a thriving technological landscape.


Revision 3r3 - 07 Jan 2025 - 19:26:37 - LinusKatzenbach
Revision 2r2 - 16 Nov 2024 - 14:56:09 - EbenMoglen
Revision 1r1 - 25 Oct 2024 - 15:18:59 - LinusKatzenbach
This site is powered by the TWiki collaboration platform.
All material on this collaboration platform is the property of the contributing authors.
All material marked as authored by Eben Moglen is available under the license terms CC-BY-SA version 4.
Syndicate this site RSSATOM