Law in Contemporary Society
It is strongly recommended that you include your outline in the body of your essay by using the outline as section titles. The headings below are there to remind you how section and subsection titles are formatted.

Can Market Integration and Community Size Explain Criticism of Strategic Defaults?

-- By BrookSutton - 06 Apr 2010

Introduction

A recent paper entitled “Markets, Religion, Community Size, and the Evolution of Fairness and Punishment” may help explain the opprobrium directed at U.S. homeowners who have walked away from their underwater mortgages.

The authors of “Markets” seek to uncover the evolutionary mechanisms underlying the dramatic expansion of human communities from small kin-based foraging bands into complex, intensively cooperative societies comprised of large, unrelated groups. They propose that this transformation depended on the development of new norms and institutions that promoted trust and fairness in commercial interactions between strangers. By lowering transaction costs associated with distrust, societies were able to achieve more productive distributions of knowledge, skills and resources and could better sustain large-scale cooperative enterprises. This essay will argue that the same mechanisms are at work in the debate over strategic defaults.

The Researchers' Findings

The authors of “Markets” support their proposition with data collected from experiments conducted among 2148 subjects representing fifteen diverse sample populations. To test their theories, they placed participants in one of three variations of an anonymous, one-off interaction in which one subject received a sum of money and had the option of offering a share of it to a second participant. The first variation, called the Dictator Game, measured the level of offers where the party controlling them was immune from sanction. The Ultimatum Game and the Third-Party Punishment Game allowed a second or third party, respectively, to surrender all or some of a share of the stake in order to punish the controlling player for making an unfair offer. In the Dictator Game the researchers found that more equitable allotments correlated with greater market integration of the sample population. Individuals who obtained a larger percentage of their daily sustenance through commerce generally shared more of the money, even though a decision to keep the entire amount served their best economic interest. Data from the Ultimatum and Third-Party Punishment games showed that subjects from bigger communities were more willing than those from smaller communities to forego all or some of a potential payoff in order to penalize an unequal apportionment of the stake.

Three themes emerge. First, individuals in market-based societies are conditioned to act equitably in transactions, even where such action defeats their self-interest. Second, members of large populations are willing to disadvantage themselves in order to penalize actors who profit disproportionately from an exchange. Finally, the expectation of fairness and the willingness to punish unfairness are the result of evolutionary processes that reward the reduction of distrust in commercial interactions. These themes support an inference that large, market-based societies will reject transactions that create disparity. However, a concern arises that the assumption of fairness essential to the development of large societies may subvert the application of punishment in transactions that are relatively opaque.

An Alternative to Caveat Emptor

The moral ambivalence characteristic of the public debate over strategic defaults may reflect the above concern. On first glance, criticism of homeowners who walk out on their underwater mortgages tends to invoke principles of caveat emptor and resists the authors’ conclusion that members of large, market-based societies are conditioned to seek and enforce equitable outcomes in commercial transactions. Critics of strategic default frequently argue that a homeowner has an obligation to continue payments on a mortgage regardless of the financial burdens that doing so would impose. While moral objections often exculpate homebuyers who were victims of facially abusive industry practices, critics otherwise affirm the disparity of wealth that would result where homeowners who bought or refinanced near the market peak continue to make payments. This judgment holds even though many homebuyers paid considerably more for their homes than they were worth; analysts predict properties in states like California and Florida may not reach their 2006 peaks for another twenty years. By implication, moral arguments against strategic default validate the substantial profits that the mortgage industry reaped by encouraging borrowers to overextend themselves in an overheated market. Additionally, they reject the premise that both parties to a mortgage assume the risk of declining home values, thereby diminishing the sense that a home purchase is a cooperative enterprise. As a result, critics of strategic default advocate asymmetrical outcomes that appear to contradict predictions based on the themes discussed above.

However, the researchers’ work in “Markets” points to an alternative framework for understanding objections to strategic default. In order to warrant punishment it follows that a transaction must appear unfair. In their experiments the researchers facilitated moral judgments by abstracting from real-world exchanges, which typically introduce variable relational coefficients into the fairness equation--information involving, for instance, the presumptive motives of contracting parties or the type of transaction. Relational information has the potential to cloud assessments of fairness by operating on an observer’s perception of the terms of an exchange. This effect seems particularly likely where interactions involve complex or ambiguous relational factors. For example, an underwater homeowner might be a speculator seeking a quick profit or a young family looking to buy into the American dream. Likewise, a voluntary default will often punish a relatively innocent third-party investor, such as a pension fund, not the party that got the better of the deal. Where ambiguity persists, the underlying presumption of fairness integral to the development of large, heterogeneous societies may engender a default moral judgment that an exchange is fair, even if it produces substantial disparity.

Conclusion

Accordingly, in transactions involving especially complex relational factors, the confusion created could systematically negate the moral instinct to penalize unfairness. This proposition leads to the ironic conclusion that large, market-based societies will tolerate grossly inequitable outcomes, at least in relatively complicated interactions, precisely because a sense of fairness is so deeply ingrained. On the other hand, the research reported in “Markets” suggests that the moral impulse to favor fairness over profit is fundamental to those societies, representing a powerful instrument for achieving justice.

Sorry I didn't comment on this earlier.

I think the paper brings up two questions. First, does the fact that people in large commerce based societies favor equitable transactions mean it is totally environmental? What is the reward mechanism in the Pavlonian experiment that produces such "fair" behavior? Can growth in GDP per capita explain some reward distributed throughout the entire society that encourages such behavior?

Second, I don't think "fairness" is a universal term that can apply the same in all societies. We are all well aware of the east/west cultural dichotomy, and such binary cultures can produce two separate ideas of "fairness".

No problem. Gives me something to do on a day with no baseball games to watch.

With respect to your first question, I think it would be an overstatement to say fairness is totally environmental. However the environment, or rather people's interaction with it over time seems to matter. Norms tend to be self-reinforcing, so where fairness norms emerged as a result of evolutionary pressures that were no doubt influenced by environmental factors, it makes sense to say fairness took root. The reward mechanism, which is really backward-looking in evolutionary logic, looks to be a greater capacity to organize group activity like agriculture or war. This outcome predictably increased each individual member's chances of passing on their genes. Such evolutionary success can be expected to reaffirm the norms underlying it. I think growth in per capita GDP acts as a reinforcement mechanism in precisely this manner. Where, on average, people feel like they have shared in the overall group success, they are less inclined to challenge the status quo. Add to this the fact that they are the sons and daughters of parents selected on the basis of their fair-mindedness. Obviously, there is a large income disparity in America, home to the population exhibiting the greatest fairness in the study. My essay hopes to offer a plausible explanation for this counterintuitive outcome.

Regarding the second question, I believe the geographical diversity of the sample populations gives good cause to believe that fairness, defined conservatively as an inclination toward equitable distribution of "gifted" wealth, does positively correlate with community size and market integration across cultures. What's interesting to me regarding the culture question is that religion, which appears in the title of the study but really nowhere in my essay, more or less drops out as a significant contributing factor in the fairness of a sample population.

Anyway, I hope you're enjoying Bethesda and staying in shape for flag football. This is our year.


You are entitled to restrict access to your paper if you want to. But we all derive immense benefit from reading one another's work, and I hope you won't feel the need unless the subject matter is personal and its disclosure would be harmful or undesirable. To restrict access to your paper simply delete the "#" on the next line:

# * Set ALLOWTOPICVIEW = TWikiAdminGroup, BrookSutton

Note: TWiki has strict formatting rules. Make sure you preserve the three spaces, asterisk, and extra space at the beginning of that line. If you wish to give access to any other users simply add them to the comma separated list

Navigation

Webs Webs

r8 - 15 Jul 2010 - 00:26:18 - BrookSutton
This site is powered by the TWiki collaboration platform.
All material on this collaboration platform is the property of the contributing authors.
All material marked as authored by Eben Moglen is available under the license terms CC-BY-SA version 4.
Syndicate this site RSSATOM